Category Archives: economics

Plus or minus three standard deviations is not all there is

As a rule of thumb, we can think about most data being in a certain range, given the variability of the data.  There are very few ten feet tall people, for example.  But the assumptions of the normal distribution apply sometimes (heights) but not always.  This is especially true in financial markets and gave rise to many books, including the Black Swan (the book, not the movie).  Today, oil prices moved down, and when compared to the recent movements in the market, the change was over five standard deviations.  Although it rarely happens, it happens all the time, because parts of the world are not normal.

Regressions in The Atlantic (who would have thought?)

Interesting article in The Atlantic about how unions affect state economies.  Some scatterplots with regression lines (but no regression statistics, alas) and some correlation coefficients.  Geek stuff, for sure.

Some observations, though.  First scatterplot shows union participation rate as the independent variable and then the “income level” as the dependent variable.  It seems that this is per capita income, but it is not clear if it is mean or median.  The choice could be quite important.

If you look at the states on the left (lower income) part of the graph versus the right (higher income) part of the graph, what might you wonder about?  How about the cost of living in each of the states?  As our business school students quickly realize, the same salary offer in NYC versus other locations means a potentially significant difference in discretionary income.

The article does a clever academic bait-and-switch (I learned how to do this in graduate school).  The article starts talking about public sector unions, but then quickly drops the “public sector” part and does all of the statistical work about unions (both private and public).  Why do this?  One, it might be easier to get the data.  Another is that using the data set that is more appropriate does not tell the right story.  (note: I am not saying that is what the author is doing, but that alarm goes off in my head when I see data that really doesn’t fit being used in an argument.)

Here’s a quote from the paper:

To put it baldly, unions are associated with the country’s economic winners, not its losers.   And it’s not that unionized states work more–unionization is negatively correlated with hours worked (-.36). States with higher levels of union membership work less hours per week but make more money–higher levels of union memberships are positively correlated with wage per hour (.48).

Now suppose this is the union for a successful private company.  We are describing a classic win-win here, right?  Everyone is sharing in the success of the company (although I know some will wonder whether management is getting more than their share – that’s for another discussion).  And less hours/more pay only works if customers of the company will continue to buy the product at the price the company tries to charge.

Now suppose we say the same thing for public workers.  Less hours, paid more.  Who is paying?  And are they getting value for that?  Could be.  But maybe not.  So do these two correlation coefficients allow us to make “bald” assertions like this?  Maybe not…

Can you see the problems with the other two scatterplots?  What does the author claim they “show?”  Are there reasonable other explanations for the relationships?  Hidden variables (like state cost of living I mentioned above)?

What does free mean?

I don’t have very many, but the ios/droid app marketplace is interesting with all the free apps.  I find myself hesitating to pay money for an app, even though having it would be quite useful and I get that the person who wrote it is trying to make a living.  I’ll drop $2 on a cup of coffee, but resist paying 99 cents for a app I know I’ll use?

The I saw this article about trying to monetize blogging and was taken by this quote:

If you are not paying for it, you’re not the customer; you’re the product being sold.

 Interesting thought now when loading a free app.  Do you wonder who is buying you?

Graphs can say one thing, or another

First, I am not posting this to make any statement about Paul Krugman, or anything like that.  But when comparing time series data, choosing the starting point can be more imporant than it seems, as this blogger demonstrates.  You could imagine investing strategies being compared in a similar fashion.  One graph shows strategy A is better, but with the same data and a different start date, another graph would show that strategy B is better. 

Another issue is the choice of the other data sets – they can also be chosen to look “fair” but those time series contain special features that make the analysis less than fair.  For example, compare company X with specially chosen company Y, because of the special charges for Y in a particular quarter make some observation about X seem more true.

Simple comparisons are not always so simple.

Financial collapse

First, know that I am not especially savvy about financial instruments. I sort of understand puts and calls, but not some of the financial instruments that are all over the news. And you can read lots of articles from people who think these people or those people are responsible for the mess. And some that civilization is coming to an end in deflation or hyperinflation.

Second, know that I am not a stockholder in JPMorgan Chase, although I do have one of their credit cards.

But I read this (long) letter from the CEO of JPMorgan Chase to his shareholders and came away feeling like it was one of the more honest assessments I’ve read in a while. The part that interested me starts on page nine. I think I will come back to it in a year or two and see how Mr. Dimon’s analysis has held up.

Dilbert economics and a decision tree

Scott Adams has an interesting blog where he tries to reason his way through some of the issues of the day (a bit more seriously than in his cartoons). He has been blogging about all of the decisions associated with building his new house, and one of the big decisions is whether or not to use solar power.

Here is a post where he recognizes that the usual analysis (decision) about solar is just a choice of yes or no. This sounds okay, because you’re in the middle of building the house and have to make a decision, right?

Well, there’s another branch that people often overlook – wait and retrofit solar later. Nice observation, especially since that branch may be the best one.

I also can’t help but smile when I read the summary:

My new home will have solar power. It was a city requirement. I plan to brag about it to people who are passionate about the environment and bad at math.

Sometimes a really smart person talks about things

Ok, so there’s lots of blogging and arguing and anxiety about health care. Most of what I read is relatively unhelpful, and some of it is downright misleading. I don’t know whether the mis-leaders are doing it on purpose or not (they might not know either).

Dean Kamen, on the other hand, is a pretty smart guy. I think you’ll have a different appreciation for the debate after reading this Popular Mechanics piece.

Maybe some economic modeling next time first?

Here’s a good quiz. I thought of another, operations version:

You’re the gate agent for Delta and the flight is overbooked by two people. You announce in the gate area that anyone who wants to take a later flight should get in line. You’ll give everyone who volunteers a $1000 voucher for future travel on Delta. After you’ve given four vouchers, and you realize there are ten people still in line, do you call you boss to see if you can continue to give out vouchers? Or do you realize you probably should have offered $100 vouchers?

Just wondering.